Reviewing the Diversification Issues
Reviewing the Diversification Issues
When a national or global aggregate time series is constructed from the contributions of thousands or even millions of agents, a natural question arises: Why don't their idiosyncratic shocks cancel out?
The intuition suggests that the volatility of such a time series should decrease as , where is the number of agents. This decay rate is typical in a population of agents with additive Gaussian fluctuations. This concept is often referenced, as seen in the observation by Lucas (1977): "... in a complex modern economy, there will be a large number of such shifts in any given period, each small in importance relative to total output. There will be much 'averaging out' of such effects across markets."
Aggregate Standard Deviation
Is the magnitude of the aggregate standard deviation approximately ? If not, why?
A quick response is that it is not, because all agents can experience growth or decline due to an 'aggregate shock' that exceeds . Lucas (1977) also noted: "... there have been many instances of shocks to supply which affect all, or many, sectors of the economy simultaneously. Such shocks will not cancel in the way I have described, and they will induce output fluctuations in the aggregate."
The question then becomes whether the idiosyncratic part of aggregate volatility follows a rule. The answer is that it declines more mildly, but this issue requires a careful approach.
Variance and Covariance in Sectoral Fluctuations
Consider a partition of firms into sectors with mild fluctuations. From previous equations, the variance of the log of is approximately:
where denote pairs of parts . Sectoral log fluctuations can be expressed as . Thus, the covariance is:
This equation contains elements to be summed for aggregate variance. In special cases, this expression simplifies, providing insights into real-life settings.
Uncorrelated Shocks and Unit Variance
For uncorrelated shocks of unit variance, (Kronecker's delta), the equation simplifies to:
If time series are uncorrelated with idiosyncratic shocks, then:
Aggregate and Idiosyncratic Shocks
Aggregate shocks and idiosyncratic shocks both contribute to aggregate volatility, and either can dominate. Early solutions assumed idiosyncratic variance vanishes at a rate , yet empirical evidence shows a milder decay.
If all parts share a single term:
For parts of nearly equal size, , the sum yields:
Linear variance is:
Effective Number of Agents
The effective number of agents may be less than the actual number , due to the concentration of contributions among a few large agents. For example, 100 companies might account for half the exports, and 10,000 for the other half, leading to , not .
Idiosyncratic Variance Decay
Gabaix (2011) suggests a power law size distribution leads to a milder decay . However, this is derived for the Herfindahl index and not directly applicable to aggregate idiosyncratic variance. The assumption that is constant across agents is unrealistic.
The proposition in Gabaix (2011) should be limited to Herfindahl index decay, not aggregate idiosyncratic variance. Further investigation is needed to understand the decay of idiosyncratic variance with population size.
In subsequent sections, tools are provided for studying the dependence, showing how nonlinearities contribute to comovement terms among agents.